• Since 2020Q2, actual consumption has been below desired. The gap between the two—a measure of pent-up demand—explains in large part the incredible resilience of the Canadian economy to the rapid rise in interest rates.
  • Low and accommodative real interest rates, record low unemployment, combined with increased net wealth through rising home equity and excess savings and high oil prices drove a substantial increase in Canadians’ desired level of consumption. As these factors began normalizing and reversing, desired consumption has subsequently declined, with most of the adjustment so far attributable to monetary tightening and restrictive real rates.
  • Supply bottlenecks have on the other hand limited Canadians’ ability to increase their actual consumption to fulfill their desired level. As supply bottlenecks resolve, actual consumption increases and the gap between actual and desired consumption narrows.
  • The Bank of Canada needs to eliminate this pent-up demand in order to move the economy into excess supply and alleviate inflationary pressures. We expect this to occur in 2024Q2, at which point the BoC will be able to gradually reduce its policy rate.

The Canadian economy has been incredibly resilient in the face of rapidly rising interest rates. Much of this surprising strength can be ascribed to pent-up demand—a measure of the gap between actual and desired consumption—amongst a broad range of things, including increased wealth and population growth. While all three factors are linked, this note focuses on pent-up demand as a source of economic resilience. We investigate the drivers of desired and actual consumption, how they have evolved over time and throughout the forecast horizon, and the net impact on pent-up demand. Desired consumption is our measure of households’ optimal level of consumption which we estimate based on different economic fundamentals like income, interest rates, and wealth (see appendix for full list).

During the pandemic, the gap between actual and desired consumption grew larger (charts 1 and 2). Low and accommodative interest rates, easy access to credit, strong labour market recovery and record low unemployment, combined with increased net wealth through rising home equity and excess savings and high oil prices, drove a substantial increase in Canadians’ desired level of consumption. On the other hand, supply constraints and public health rules hampered their ability to increase their actual consumption to fulfill the desired level. 

Chart 1: Consumption; Chart 2: Pent-Up Demand

Despite the BoC’s efforts to slow the economy to alleviate inflationary pressures by rapidly and aggressively hiking its policy rate, the gap between actual and desired consumption has remained negative (a more negative gap means more pent-up demand). This persistence of pent-up demand explains in large part why the economy has been incredibly resilient in the face of many headwinds including tighter monetary policy. As a result, the real policy rate must remain in restrictive territory until pent-up demand and the upward pressure it creates on the output gap and inflation is alleviated.

Note that our equation for desired consumption does not capture financial wealth, which increased during the pandemic through an accumulation of savings and deposits as governments rolled out fiscal supports with restrictions on spending due to lockdowns. This financial wealth effect might add to the level of desired consumption as some households have a large amount of liquid savings to support their spending in the face of higher rates, leading to potentially higher and more persistent pent-up demand than estimated by our model.

FACTORS BEHIND PENT-UP DEMAND

1. Interest Rates

The onset of the pandemic brought with it ultra low real rates as governments and central banks across the globe reacted to support households and financial markets through lockdowns and other pandemic related measures. Such low and accommodative rates naturally increase the level of desired consumption as households have easier access to credit.

Even as the BoC began raising its policy rates at the start of 2022, hiking by a cumulative 400 bps that year alone, the real rate—the one that matters for economic growth, measured as the nominal rate minus the expected inflation rate—remained negative throughout 2022 as inflation roared. The real rate was still in accommodative territory in the first quarter of 2023, only rising above its neutral level of 0.5% in the second quarter of 2023.

Only when real rates began to increase did pent-up demand begin to ease as rising real rates reduced the level of desired consumption (chart 3). In fact, a large proportion of the elimination of pent-up demand so far can be explained by the fall of desired consumption driven by higher real rates. Given the persistence of pent-up demand, however, an episode of persistent positive real rates is needed to entirely eliminate it, considering the lag in the transmission of real rates to desired consumption. As shown in chart 3, we are forecasting real rates to begin declining right around the elimination of pent-up demand in 2024Q2.

Chart 3: Pent-Up Demand and Real Policy Rates

2. Strong Labour Market Recovery

The post-pandemic labour market recovery has been nothing short of incredible. Canada has added almost a million jobs (in seasonally adjusted terms) since the onset of the pandemic, with the unemployment rate reaching record lows. This strength in the labour market and low unemployment has acted as a support for the Canadian economy as households were able to hold on to their jobs and incomes in an environment of uncertainty and rising prices and rates.

The level of desired consumption subsequently increased as more jobs were added to the economy and the unemployment rate moved towards and eventually fell below its equilibrium level—often referred to as the NAIRU, the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment—adding to pent-up demand and of course, inflationary pressures (chart 4). As the gap between the unemployment rate and its equilibrium level began narrowing again, so did the gap between actual and desired consumption. 

Chart 4: Pent-Up Demand and Unemployment

3. Home Prices and Wealth Effect

It is no secret that since the start of the pandemic and up to 2022Q1, home prices in Canada soared, not only in nominal terms but also in real terms (i.e., when adjusted for inflation). With much of Canadian households’ wealth attached to housing, this increase in home prices translated to an increase in net wealth which directly impacted households’ level of desired consumption and in turn pent-up demand, bringing both up (chart 5—note that home prices relative to 2020Q1 are inverted. A negative number means home prices are higher than in 2020Q1). Real housing prices only started to decline relative to the start of the pandemic when the BoC began its hiking cycle in 2022Q1, bringing desired consumption and pent-up demand down with it.

Chart 5: Pent Up Demand and Real Housing Prices

4. Oil Prices and Wealth Effect

A big driver of inflation following the onset of the pandemic had been the surge in oil prices, brought about by supply shortages and significantly exacerbated by the Russia-Ukraine war that began in February of 2022. This affected the Canadian economy differently than others given its status as one of the world’s largest oil producers and net exporters.

While households had to grapple with higher gas and energy bills, higher oil prices were on net a positive to the Canadian economy as they boosted the terms of trade, creating a positive wealth effect, and supported investment and employment in oil producing provinces. This in turn increased desired consumption and pent-up demand (chart 6—note that oil prices relative to 2020Q1 are inverted. A negative number means oil prices are higher than in 2020Q1). As oil prices began normalizing, desired consumption and the gap with actual consumption narrowed.

Chart 6: Pent-Up Demand and Real Oil Prices

THE ROLE OF SUPPLY CONSTRAINTS

Another prominent feature of the pandemic era has been supply bottlenecks. The pandemic disrupted global supply chains and created shortages across all consumer goods resulting from lockdowns and border closures. This meant that even as Canadians desired to consume more, they were unable to do so as anything from furniture to bikes to cars was unavailable for purchase. This lowered the level of actual consumption while factors discussed above boosted desired, further widening the gap between the two and exacerbating pent-up demand (chart 7—a higher supplier deliveries index means faster delivery times while a lower index means slower delivery times and more supply bottlenecks). 

Chart 7: Pent-Up Demand and Supply Delivery Times

As supply constraints started to improve, pent-up demand started to close as Canadians were able to consume more to fulfill their desired level of consumption.

Given the initial strength of desired consumption and the inability of actual consumption to catch up due to supply constraints, pent-up demand has persisted despite rising rates and other headwinds, explaining in large part the resilience of the economy so far that had forecasts of recessions repeatedly pushed out. Looking ahead, we expect pent-up demand to wind up by early next year, mostly driven by a lowering of desired consumption as actual consumption continues to increase to catch up, albeit, at a slower pace than seen since supply bottlenecks eased.

MONETARY POLICY IMPLICATIONS

The Bank of Canada needs to eliminate pent-up demand, which is at the root of the recent resilience of the Canadian economy, in order to create an episode of excess supply and alleviate inflationary pressures to bring inflation back to its 2% target. We forecast pent-up demand to be eliminated by the second quarter of 2024, largely driven by higher real rates and lower desired consumption as a result. Only then will the BoC be able to start gradually reducing its policy rate without undermining its efforts to tame inflation.

 

APPENDIX

We estimate the level of current desired consumption based on economic fundamentals like income, interest rates and wealth. We also estimate a dynamic equation to forecast actual consumption which features forward-looking behaviour, with agents attempting to optimally set their consumption to equal the desired path, in the face of adjustment costs and conditional on the expected evolution of many economic drivers.

The drivers of desired consumption (sign of the effect in parenthesis):

  • Disposable income (+)
  • Real policy rate (-)
  • Unemployment Rate (-)
  • Real oil price (+)
  • Real housing prices (+)
  • Potential GDP (+)
  • Debt/GDP (to capture fiscal transfers) (+)

 

The drivers of actual consumption:

  • Desired consumption (+)
  • Real policy rate (-)
  • Disposable income (+)
  • Real exchange rate real (-)
  • Real oil price (+)
  • Stock market (+)